Ken Steiglitz
Miscellaneous blog-like stuff
January 9, 2008:
A sniper with a machine gun
The following activity appeared on eBay Dec 3, 2007.
Closing time was 15:40:00, and the winning bid was the
three-second snipe by X**X (eBay did not anonymize the winner,
but I do here.)
> Bidder Bid Amount Bid Time
>
> X**X ( 529) US $422.00 Dec-03-07 15:39:57 PST
> a***t( 94) US $417.00 Dec-03-07 15:39:56 PST
> a***t( 94) US $412.00 Dec-03-07 15:39:55 PST
> a***t( 94) US $407.00 Dec-03-07 15:39:54 PST
> a***t( 94) US $402.00 Dec-03-07 15:39:52 PST
> a***t( 94) US $397.00 Dec-03-07 15:39:51 PST
> a***t( 94) US $392.00 Dec-03-07 15:39:43 PST
> a***t( 94) US $387.00 Dec-03-07 15:39:41 PST
> a***t( 94) US $382.00 Dec-03-07 15:39:33 PST
> a***t( 94) US $377.00 Dec-03-07 15:39:31 PST
> a***t( 94) US $372.00 Dec-03-07 15:39:28 PST
> a***t( 94) US $367.00 Dec-03-07 15:27:50 PST
> a***t( 94) US $362.00 Nov-30-07 20:00:08 PST
> 6***6( 404) US $350.00 Nov-29-07 09:35:24 PST
> a***t( 94) US $303.00 Nov-28-07 04:28:58 PST
> r***n( 94) US $201.00 Nov-27-07 22:17:33 PST
> a***t( 94) US $200.00 Nov-27-07 11:27:29 PST
> 3***o( 35) US $101.00 Nov-26-07 17:45:20 PST
> d***m( 7 ) US $52.00 Nov-26-07 17:11:29 PST
> Starting Price US $0.99 Nov-26-07 15:40:00 PST
What surprises me is the final blast of 11 bids by a***t, some
only one second apart, and all $5.00 apart (eBay's bidding
increment in this range). This was probably done with sniping
software, but it's possible that 11 windows were opened up
and the forms filled out in advance. But why would anyone
do this? Here are two possible explanations:
1. Intimidation. Such repeated bids by the current high bidder
might be meant to scare away competitors by suggesting that she
is raising her bid very high above the current posted price.
Moreover, this mechanized barrage for the last 30 seconds may
also be meant to confuse as well as intimidate competitors.
2. Advertizing. Such repeated bids might be used by the seller
to raise the total number of bids on the item, and so attract
attention to the item---a motive exactly opposite to intimidation.
But I think this would only make sense earlier in the auction.
The first explanation seems more convincing to me than the second.
Any other suggestions?
October 31, 2007:
ebay's transparency: The weather clears a bit
It is once again possible to search by bidder on auctions
that are still active. Thanks to Jon Edwards for pointing
this out to me.
There is an advantage and disadvantage to eBay in allowing this
"shadowing," and I can only speculate on their motivation
for first allowing the option, then turning it off, and then
restoring it.
The visibility of bidders is clearly a deterrent
to shill bidding by sellers---and allowing them to be seen even before
the close of an auction is more of a deterrent than allowing them
to be seen only after the close. However, this makes it possible
for interlopers to send offers of competing sales to early bidders before
the close of an auction, and eBay was evidently trying to crack down on
this interference when they turned off the option. That was around the
beginning of 2007. Apparently the balance tipped the other way, and it was
felt best to restore the option. It means that once again, some bidders can ride
on the shoulders of others, trying to take advantage of their search time and
expertize.
Another reason not to bid early!
September 26, 2007
The ethics of finding an equilibrium
Bidder rings, or any form of explicit collusion between bidders to reduce
competition in an auction, are generally illegal, certainly unethical, and against eBay's
rules. I recently mentioned the phenomenon to a lawyer, at a cocktail party,
and he immediately came back with the suggestion that bidders could form an LLC
and bid collectively, presumably disbursing won items in some way to the LLC's
officers. When I mentioned this to Ed Felten, he suggested that this might be
an illegal restraint of trade. These exchanges got me thinking about just
where and how a line can be drawn. For example, can a corporation enter a bid
to an auction house like Sotheby's? The rules I've seen in auction catalogs
mention "buyer" and "bidder" without definition. What rules would then govern the dispersal
by the corporation of items that it wins at auction? Can it auction them
off to members of the corporation, thus functioning as a legally incorporated ring?
Don't agents of companies buy things at auction all the time for resale by their companies?
What about the situation in the standard kinds of games of "game theory", where
players can learn to cooperate through their moves---without explicit
collusion. To take a concrete example, suppose two bidders on eBay, A and
B, say, learn, only through bidding, that B will bid low on
odd calendar days, and A will bid low on even calendar days. I emphasize
that this is not by explicit arrangement, but by trial and error in bidding strategies.
The players are, in one sense, colluding to reduce competition. Is this legal? Ethical?
After all, in the world of game theory, this can be thought of as just the healthy
and natural attainment of a Nash equilibrium.
August 17, 2007
A student piece of mine on the technological singularity, 1959
I was looking recently at the wikipedia page for
technological singularity,
and remembered the first thing I ever published,
"The Simulation of
Human Activities by Machine, Quadrangle,
vol. 29, no. 3, College of Engineering, New York University, Jan. 1959, pp. 23-24.
It was my version of an impending intelligence explosion. It's well packed with clichés
and a bit pompous; my excuse is that I was still only 19 years old. A couple of predictions
have been borne out: I boldly predicted that "Solid-state devices will probably
replace inefficient vacuum tubes in a few years." And that "...our chess masters
will eventually be outclassed by an IBM product; probably within ten or twenty years."
Well, I got the corporation right, but rushed things a little.
June 14, 2007
Christopher Shea's Boston Globe column and blog
Thanks to Christopher Shea for his mention of my book in his nicely
crafted Critical Faculties column
"eBay-nomics" in the Boston Globe (June 10), and for his mention of
my blog in the Boston Globe's
"Brainiac" blog (June 13).
He continues his comments on the world of eBay strategy
in his entry "eBay bidders v. eBay sellers", also
in the Boston Globe's
"Brianiac" blog (June 12). In this piece he describes recent
results by Prof. Uri Simonsohn (Wharton School) on the problem faced by sellers
in choosing auction closing times on eBay. More strategic moves in response to
strategic moves. It's what makes game theory fascinating.
See also my comments on Simonsohn & Ariely's
recent working paper "When Rational Sellers Face Non-Rational Buyers:
Evidence from Herding on eBay" in the
New Literature section of this blog.
June 10, 2007
eBay's new anti-sniping feature?
eBay recently introduced a feature (Bid Assistant) that appears to function
in perfect harmony with my prediction in the June 8 entry below. It allows
bidders to schedule bids on several items, and these bids are executed
sequentially as items close, until one item is won. Here's how eBay describes the
operation of the feature:
"Once you've placed your bids, Bid Assistant will move through
your group (starting with the item that ends first), and
place bids on your behalf."
with the caveat
"You cannot schedule bids to be placed at a specific time."
So it appears that the feature will actually place bids at the
earliest opportunity, encouraging early bidding—just the oppposite
of sniping. I'll verify this interpretation and report what actually happens
when I get a chance to try it.
Note added June 10, 2007: Yes, this is indeed early-bidding heaven. I
formed a group of two items, entered my bids, and invoked Bid Assistant.
My bid on the first item was executed immediately. It was not high enough
to become current high bidder, and I received a "you were outbid" notice.
June 8, 2007
Automated sniping: A prediction
Christopher Shea of the Boston Globe, asked me the
following questions: "How do you think the sniping software
is affecting auctions? Is it useful?"
These are interesting and complex questions.
First, there is a distinction between sniping
software that people buy (or write themselves),
and sniping services like eSnipe. The latter
requires that you trust the service as
a fourth party (the third being eBay), not only
to execute your bid, but to keep your password secret.
The added security risk may be a minor worry to most
users, but may well deter others. I point out in Snipers
(p. 97) that at least one sniping service (Cniper) has captured
data from user bids, albeit anonymized and used only for academic purposes.
As for the question of whether automated sniping is useful,
if you agree with me that sniping is a good, if not optimal,
strategy in most eBay auctions, then its automation is very
useful. The main argument against it is that earlier bidding might
scare off other bidders—but I believe the weight of the evidence
points in the other direction. Early bidding attracts more bids
and higher ultimate prices. In fact, I argue in Snipers that
eBay owes much of its success to the second-price format that
encourages early bidding.
The other main argument against sniping, that it presents
the danger of your bid missing the deadline because of
last-minute network traffic, is not, in my opinion, serious.
For one thing, you can adjust the time margin for your snipe.
(I believe eSnipe uses a rather tight default of 6 seconds.)
The point is simply to get your bid in late enough so no one
can respond to it, and in practice, automated sniping gets the job done.
How is automated sniping affecting eBay? It's difficult, if
not impossible, to determine. As far as I know, automatic and manual
last-second bids are indistinguishable to the ordinary outside observer.
I have seen stern warnings from sellers about the evils of sniping, automatic
or manual. Mainly, they stress the danger of your last-second bid arriving at eBay too late.
Such warnings are a sign to me that the sellers recognize the importance
of stimulating early bidding. The fact that early bidding also works
to the advantage of eBay—for the same reasons—prompts me to make a prediction:
Despite the fact that eBay is constantly introducing what seems like an
endless progression of new features and embellishments, automatic sniping
will not be one of them.
June 7, 2007
Bidding above the Buy-It-Now-Price crazy like a fox
It may not be competely obvious that in some circumstances it is perfectly
rational for an eBay bidder to bid above the posted Buy-It-Now price.
I'll let you think about it. This is the subject of question 5.2 in snipers.
It may happen, then, that sometimes the purchase price will end up above that
Buy-It-Now-Price, but that is no reason to conclude that people have acted crazily.
June 4, 2007
eBay's transparency gets a little cloudy
A few days after the page proof for Snipers went to the printers
eBay instituted some changes that reduced the transparency of their operation.
The stated motivation, which is quite reasonable, is to make it more difficult
for interlopers to reach buyers and capture their business, or, worse, defraud them.
For one thing, it is no longer possible to search by bidder in ongoing auctions—what
I call "shadowing" in Snipers. Another important change by eBay was the removal
of bidder IDs from the bidding history when the bidding reaches $200. The listings
in these cases are anonymized as bidder 1, bidder 2, etc., just the way they
are in my plots in chapter 3, for example. To compensate (partially) for this
removal of information, a rather elaborate summary of the history of each anonymized
bidder is provided.
These changes illustrate the growing tension between complete transparency
and buyer vulnerability. The transparency is extremely important
in engendering trust. After all, eBay is above all else a trusted third
party, keeping buyers' identities and high bids secret. But safety is also crucial.
So eBay, in a continuing process of fine-tuning, is converging to a mechanism that
is translucent rather than transparent.